NOTICES

                         DEPARTMENT OF COMMERCE

                                [C-533-063]

     Certain Iron-Metal Castings From India; Final Results of Countervailing Duty
                            Administrative Review

                          Monday, December 10, 1990

 AGENCY: International Trade Administration/Import Administration Commerce.

 ACTION: Notice of final results of countervailing duty administrative review.

 SUMMARY: On April 5, 1990, the Department of Commerce published the preliminary
 results of its administrative review of the countervailing duty order on certain
 iron-metal castings from India. We have now completed that review and determine the net
 subsidy to be 9.81 percent ad valorem for R.B. Agarwalla, 19.32 percent ad valorem for
 Carnation, 36.40 percent ad valorem for Crescent, 78.86 percent ad valorem for Govind,
 44.84 percent ad valorem for Kajaria, 9.06 percent ad valorem for RSI, 41.87 percent ad
 valorem for Serampore and 27.37 percent ad valorem for all other firms during the period
 January 1, 1985 through December 31, 1985.

 EFFECTIVE DATE: December 10, 1990.

 FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:Philip Pia or Paul McGarr, Office of Countervailing
 Compliance, International Trade Administration, U.S. Department of Commerce,
 Washington, DC 20230; telephone: (202) 377-2786.

 SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION:

 Background

 On April 5, 1990, the Department of Commerce (the Department) published in the Federal
 Register (55 FR 12702) the preliminary results of its administrative review of the
 countervailing duty order on certain iron-metal castings from India (October 16, 1980;
 46 FR 16921). The Department has now completed that administrative review in
 accordance with section 751 of the Tariff Act of 1930 (the Tariff Act).

 Scope of Review

 Imports covered by the review are shipments of Indian manhole covers and frames,
 clean-out covers and frames, and catch basin grates and frames. These articles are
 commonly called municipal or public works castings and are used for access or for drainage
 for public utility, water, and sanitary systems. During the review period, such merchandise
 was classifiable under Tariff Schedules of the United States Annotated (TSUSA) item
 numbers 657.0950 and 657.0990. These products are currently classifiable under item
 numbers 7325.10.0010 and 7325.10.0050 of the Harmonized Tariff Schedule (HTS). The
 TSUSA and HTS item numbers are provided for convenience and Customs purposes. The
 written description remains dispositive.

 The review covers the period January 1, 1985 through December 31, 1985 and ten
 programs: (1) International Price Reimbursement Scheme (IPRS), (2) Cash Compensatory
 Support program (CCS), (3) pre-shipment export loans, (4) post- shipment financing, (5)
 income tax reductions, (6) Market Development Assistance (MDA) grants, (7) sale of import
 replenishment licenses, (8) extension of free trade zones, (9) preferential freight rates, and
 (10) import duty exemptions available to 100 percent export-oriented units.

 Analysis of Comments Received

 We gave interested parties an opportunity to comment on the preliminary results. We
 received comments from the Indian exporters, U.S. importers and the petitioner, Pinkerton
 Foundry.

 Comment 1: The exporters and importers argue that IPRS payments are not countervailable
 subsidies. In intent and practice, the IPRS refunds to exporters of castings the difference
 between the price they must pay for certain raw materials purchased from
 government-owned Indian producers and the price they would otherwise pay on the world
 market. It was operated in a manner consistent with item (d) of the Illustrative List of
 Export Subsidies annexed to the Agreement on Interpretation and Application of Articles
 VI, XVI, and XXIII of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (the List) which states:
 The delivery by governments or their agencies of imported or domestic products or
 services for use in the production of exported goods, on terms or conditions more
 favorable than for delivery of like or directly competitive products or services for use in the
 production of goods for domestic consumption, if (in the case of products) such terms or
 conditions are more favorable than those commercially available on world markets to their
 exporters (emphasis added).
 Item (d) of the List is thus explicit that the provision of raw materials at world market prices
 to exporters is not a subsidy. The Department recognized this in previous countervailing
 duty cases, namely in Final Negative Countervailing Duty Determination; Certain Steel
 Wire Nails from the Republic of Korea (47 FR 39549; September 8, 1982), the Department
 held that "price preferences for inputs to be used in the production of export goods
 constitute a subsidy only if the preference lowers the price of that input below that which
 the input purchaser would pay on world markets." Similarly, in Final Negative
 Countervailing Duty Determination; Oil Country Tubular Goods from Taiwan (51 FR
 19583; May 30, 1986), the Department stated that:
 Based on an examination of China Steel's second-tier prices for hot-rolled coil used in the
 production of OCTG, and of the world market prices for such coil, we found that China Steel's
 prices were at world market levels; therefore, we determine that China Steel's two-tiered
 pricing policy does not confer a countervailable benefit within the meaning of the
 countervailing duty law.
 Furthermore, the exporters state that there is no evidence in the statutes or in the
 legislative history to support a theory that Congress intended to reject the principle
 embodied in item (d) of the List when it enacted the Trade Agreements Act of 1979 (the
 TAA). In fact, the importers claim that this issue was examined by the U.S. Treasury
 Department in a countervailing duty investigation that predates the 1979 statute (see,
 Final Countervailing Duty Determination; Leather Wearing Apparel from Uruguay (43
 FR 3974; January 30, 1978). According to the importers, Treasury determined that direct
 payments to exporters of apparel that lowered the price of their primary 

*50748

 input,
 hides, to the "readily available price of hides in other markets" was not a subsidy.
 The exporters also argue that the IPRS benefits not the exporter of castings, but rather the
 Indian pig iron producers. Castings exporters can import pig iron or purchase domestic pig
 iron at the relatively high price that is set by the Indian government and receive IPRS
 rebates. The net effects of these two alternatives are the same.
 In addition, importers argue that the Department is attempting to use an unauthorized
 interpretation of U.S. law to find the Indian IPRS program countervailable. In Certain
 Cotton Yarn Products from Brazil; Final Results of Countervailing Duty Administrative
 Review (55 FR 3442; February 1, 1990), the Department determined as countervailable a
 similar Brazilian dual pricing scheme, the Price Equalization Program (PEP). In Cotton Yarn,
 the Department advanced the theory that the List is not controlling on the identification of
 subsidies: "It is irrelevant whether the PEP is consistent with item (d) or whether cotton
 yarn exporters could have imported raw cotton at world market prices. We are concerned
 with the alternative price commercially available in the domestic market" (55 FR 3446).
 Importers argue that such a theory is untenable because Congress incorporated the List
 into U.S. countervailing duty law and the Department has no authority to claim item (d)
 as "irrelevant." The Court of International Trade (CIT) has acknowledged this adoption of the
 List in U.S. law in its decision in Fabricas El Carmen, S.A. de C.V., et al. v. United States, Slip
 Op. 87-113 (CIT October 7, 1987), as did the U.S. Court of Appeals in its decision of the 1984
 review of this countervailing duty order (see RSI (India) Pvt., Ltd. v. United States,
 687 F.2d 1571 (Fed. Cir. 1989)). The legislative history confirms that the sole reservation
 expressed by Congress in adopting the List was that it not be regarded as a permanent,
 exhaustive listing of all export subsidies countervailable under U.S. law. The Department is
 empowered only to supplement or expand the existing List, not alter or ignore established
 principles of the List. Consequently, in the case of item (d), U.S. law specifically excludes
 from countervailability any such programs which do not result in the provision of inputs on
 terms more favorable than those obtainable on world markets. Furthermore, the
 Department's failure to observe the principle of the statutory language and item (d) also
 directly conflicts with its efforts to codify item (d) in its own regulations. Commerce's
 proposed Regulation 355.44(h) in 19 CFR part 355 Countervailing Duties; Notice of
 Proposed Rulemaking and Request for Public Comments (54 FR 23366; May 31, 1989)
 clearly states that price preferences for inputs used in the production of goods for export
 are subsidies only if they are provided on terms or conditions that "are more favorable than
 those commercially available on world markets to their exporters."
 Conversely, petitioner argues that the IPRS is a countervailable subsidy because the
 exception in item (d) applies only to the preferential pricing of inputs and not to payments
 contingent upon the exportation of finished goods. Petitioner maintains that the
 Department's interpretation of item (d) has always been a narrow one, i.e., the exception in
 item (d) applies only to inputs, not monetary payments. Such an interpretation of item (d) is
 consistent with a panel report of the GATT Committee on Subsidies and Countervailing
 Measures that examined item (d) in conjunction with an investigation of European
 Community pasta export payments. See GATT Panel Report on EEC Subsidies on Export
 Pasta Products, SCM/433 (May 19, 1983). The Department's determination in Cotton Yarn,
 that the Brazilian PEP program is countervailable, is consistent with past Department
 determinations that reflect a narrow interpretation of the exception in item (d). The
 Department's preliminary determination that IPRS payments are countervailable implicitly
 recognizes that the exception in item (d) does not apply because item (d) clearly
 encompasses the IPRS within its definition of an export subsidy.

 Department's position: We disagree with the importers and exporters. The Indian
 government's decision to insulate its pig iron producers from foreign competition placed
 users of domestic pig iron at a disadvantage vis-a- vis competitors abroad by raising the
 price of domestic pig iron. During the review period, Indian castings exporters could have
 overcome this competitive disadvantage in two ways: Duty drawback and the IPRS.
 Imported pig iron in India is subject to normal customs duties. Had Indian castings
 exporters imported foreign pig iron for use as an input and processed it into castings for
 export, they could have been exempted from the normal customs duties on pig iron by
 using duty drawback, a practice acceptable under U.S. contervailing duty law and the GATT.
 Alternatively, under the IPRS, the Indian government created a benchmark price for pig
 iron and made cash payments to exporters based on the difference between the benchmark
 price and the domestic price. These cash payments were made exclusively to castings
 exporters, with the net effect being a reduction in the price of pig iron to a level well below
 the price commercially available in the domestic market. The IPRS was an instrument used
 by the Indian government to ameliorate the deleterious effects of high-price pig iron on a
 specific group of downstream users.
 The circumstances is both Korean Nails and Taiwanese OCTG differ from those in this case.
 In Korean Nails, the Korean producers of nails for export had access to wire rod from
 foreign as well as domestic sources at comparable prices. Although afforded the
 opportunity through tariff protection to charge high prices for wire rod used in the
 manufacture of products sold domestically, POSCO (an integrated steel producer which is
 largely government-owned) and other Korean producers of wire rod chose to lower their
 prices to exporters of nails and compete with foreign-sourced wire rod purchased under
 duty drawback. We concluded that "the different prices for purchasers do not arise from a
 scheme to subsidize exports, but rather are a commercial response to a segmented market,
 one segment being protected and the other fully open to foreign competition." We further
 stated that "this dual pricing system reflects strictly economic motivations (of the wire rod
 producers) rather than a desire of the Government of Korea (the owners of POSCO) to
 subsidize nail exports" (47 FR 39552).
 We noted in addition that our conclusion regarding the dual pricing system was consistent
 with the principle contained in item (d). However, our decision not to countervail the
 Korean pricing scheme was not made solely on the basis of item (d). Rather, our decision
 was based in large part on a determination that POSCO was acting in a commercially
 reasonable fashion by instituting a dual- pricing system. As support for this, we stated that
 two privately-owned Korean wire rod producers also had dual-pricing systems in place.
 These facts led us to conclude that the Korean government was not acting to subsidize
 exports.
 Similary, in Taiwanese OCTG, we found that China Steel, a state-owned corporation and a
 supplier of pipe and tube inputs, maintained a two-tiered pricing policy. Accordingly, in
 determining whether China Steel's 

*50749

 prices were preferential, we compared not only
 the actual prices FEMCO (an OCTG producer) paid China Steel to the actual prices FEMCO
 paid for imported coil, but we also compared the prices FEMCO paid China Steel to generally
 available world market prices for coil. In doing so, we found that China Steel's prices were at
 world market levels. Once again, our decision was based on a determination that China Steel
 was acting in a commercially reasonable manner.
 In this case, the fact pattern is different. The Steel Authority of India, Ltd. (SAIL), an
 Indian government entity that supplied all of the pig iron used by the castings exporters,
 did not institute a dual-pricing scheme for pig iron. Instead, the Indian government
 intervened to ensure that Indian castings exporters could continue to use
 domestically-sourced pig iron while pig iron producers continued to enjoy the full benefits
 of tariff protection. Thus, the Indian government's decision to establish the IPRS and make
 cash payments to castings producers made possible exports that otherwise would not have
 occurred. Without this direct government action, castings exporters would have had to pay
 the high domestic price for Indian pig iron.
 The fact that the Illustrative List is incorporated into U.S. law has no bearing on our
 decision. In determining whether item (d) is applicable to the identification and
 measurement of an export subsidy from this type of program, we have examined the law
 and its legislative history. Section 771(5) of the Tariff Act states, in relevant part: "the term
 'subsidy' has the same meaning as the term 'bounty or grant' as that term is used in section
 303, and includes, but is not limited to, the following: (A) Any export subsidy described in
 Annex A to the Agreement (relating to the illustrative list of export subsidies) * * *"
 (emphasis added). While Congress incorporated the Illustrative List in the statute, it did not
 limit the definition of export subsidy to the practices outlined in the List. The legislative
 history of the TAA explains, "The reference to specific subsidies in the definition is not all
 inclusive, but rather is illustrative of practices which are subsidies within the meaning of the
 word as used in the bill. The administering authority may expand upon the list of specified
 subsidies consistent with the basic definition." S. Rep. No. 96-249, 96th Cong., 1st Sess. 85
 (1979). See also Trade Agreements Act of 1979: Statements of Administrative Action, H.R.
 Doc. No. 96-153, Pt. II, 96th Cong., 1st Sess. 432 (1979). The Illustrative List is not,
 therefore, controlling of the identification and measurement of export subsidies, but must
 be considered along with other provisions of the statute and its legislative history,
 administrative practice and judicial precedent. In light of the foregoing reasons, the
 inclusion of proposed regulation 355.44(h), which corresponds to item (d) on the List, in no
 way supports the importers' position. Finally, contrary to the exporter's claim regarding
 administrative practice prior to 1979, Uruguayan Leather Apparel is not relevant to the
 exception in item (d). There was no provision of hides to apparel manufacturers by the
 Uruguayan government, nor did the Uruguayan government intervene to manipulate the
 domestic price of hides. Uruguayan leather tanners were provided payments upon the
 export of finished leather wearing apparel, and Treasury offset the amount of the payment
 to the extent that it considered of a rebate of value-added and other indirect taxes.
 We consider a government program that results in the provision of an input to exporters at
 a price lower than to producers of domestically-sold products to confer a subsidy within the
 meaning of section 771(5) of the Tariff Act. It is irrelevant whether the IPRS is consistent
 with item (d) because we are not concerned with world market prices but with the
 alternative price of pig iron commercially available in the domestic market. This, we
 determine the IPRS program to be countervailable.
 An analogy to the IPRS program is the case of export loans. In this case, as in many others,
 we have determined that export loans at preferential interest rates constitute a subsidy. In
 measuring the subsidy, we do not concern ourselves with whether firms could have
 borrowed money at commercial rates in international credit markets. The fact that, as a
 result of a government program, they borrowed from domestic sources at rates below those
 commercially available in the domestic market leads us to determine that a subsidy is
 bestowed.

 Comment 2: The exporters argue that the benefit from the IPRS program is overstated,
 claiming that it should be offset by the Engineering Goods Export Assistance Fund (EGEAF)
 and Freight Equalization Fee (FEF) levies which are included in the price of pig iron.
 Because IPRS payments include the refund of both the EGEAF and the FEF, the amounts
 paid for these two levies should be deducted from IPRS receipts to determine the net
 subsidy from this program.
 Conversely, petitioner argues that the EGEAF and the FEF levies are not allowable offsets
 under section 771(6) of the Tariff Act. These levies are included in the price of pig iron and
 are paid regardless of whether the castings produced from the purchased pig iron is sold
 domestically or exported.

 Department's position: We agree with petitioner. Section 771(6)(A) of the Tariff Act states
 that to determine the net subsidy the Department may subtract from the gross subsidy the
 amount of "any application fee, deposit, or similar payment paid in order to qualify for, or
 to receive, the benefit of the subsidy * * *." Both levies are paid by all consumers of Indian
 pig iron, not just exporters. Therefore, they do not constitute offsets to the IPRS benefits as
 defined in the statute.

 Comment 3: The exporters argue that the Department overstated the IPRS benefit received
 by Uma, because the questionnaire response shows a refund of "excess claims" that the
 Department failed to deduct from the amount of the IPRS payment.

 Department's position: Despite repeated attempts by the Department to remedy deficiencies
 in initial and supplemental questionnaire responses, the existence of Uma's refund is not
 substantiated. Therefore, we have not deducted any amount from Uma's reported receipts
 of IPRS payments.

 Comment 4: The exporters argue that the Department overstated the IPRS benefit received
 by Carnation because Carnation reported IPRS payments received on all exports to all
 markets and the Department allocated the IPRS payments over the value of subject exports
 to the United States.

 Department's position: We agree and have corrected our calculation accordingly.

 Comment 5: The exporters claim that the Department overstated the amount of IPRS
 payments received by Serampore because of an inadvertent transposition of two numbers.

 Department's position: We agree and have corrected our calculation accordingly.

 Comment 6: The petitioner claims that the Department understated the IPRS benefit to RSI
 by allocating the IPRS payments over a value of exports that included RSI's exports of
 furniture.

 Department's position: We agree and have corrected our calculation accordingly.

 Comment 7: The petitioner claims that the Department understated the amount of IPRS
 payments received by Super Castings because of a transposition of two numbers.
 
*50750

 Department's position: We agree and have corrected our calculation accordingly.

 Comment 8: The petitioner argues that a single country-wide rate should be applied to all
 exporters. Section 706(a) of the Tariff Act states, in part, that "the order may provide for
 differing countervailing duties," 19 U.S.C. section 1671(a) (emphasis added). Thus,
 Congress created a presumption in favor of country-wide rates. The exporters add that the
 Department's discretion to apply separate company-specific rates should not be exercised
 because all the companies benefit from the IPRS program to the same degree. The varying
 rates of subsidy attributable to the IPRS program led to the application of individual
 company rates not because the companies received differing rates of benefits under the
 IPRS program, but rather because the Department used IPRS payments received in 1985,
 rather than the amounts claimed on 1985 exports. Therefore, it is inappropriate to assign
 individual company rates solely because some companies, as a result of happenstance,
 received IPRS payments during the review period that were substantially different from the
 amounts claimed for exports made during the review period.
 Conversely, the importers argue that the Department correctly assigned company-specific
 rates, rather than a single country-wide rate. The Department is required by its regulations
 to issue company-specific rates if significant differentials exist between the
 weighted-average country-wide rate and individual company rates.

 Department's position: We disagree with the petitioner and the exporters. Section 607 of
 the Tariff and Trade Act of 1984 establishes a statutory presumption in favor of
 country-wide countervailing duty rates, with the possibility of company-specific rates if
 the Department determines that a "significant differential" exists between companies
 receiving subsidies benefits. 19 U.S.C. 1671e(a)(2). Pursuant to that section, the Department
 promulgated regulations to use a single weighted-average country-wide rate unless there is
 a significant differential between an individual company rate and the weighted-average
 country-wide rate. Under § 355.20(d)(3) of our regulations, a significant differential is a
 "difference of the greater of at least five percentage points or 25 percent, from the
 weighted-average net subsidy calculated on a country-wide basis." In this review, seven
 companies met the standard in the regulations for being significantly different; therefore,
 we assigned them company-specific rates.
 Regarding the exporters' argument that it is inappropriate to assign company-specific rates
 solely because lagged receipts of IPRS payments resulted in varying subsidies for individual
 companies, the Department has consistently used receipts and not claims filed during the
 review period to measure the subsidy from the IPRS program. We use receipts because they
 represent a tangible measure of benefits received. Claims, on the other hand, are tenuous in
 nature and have the potential to be rejected.
 As a result of the changes in our calculations discussed in Comments 4 through 7, we
 determine the net subsidy from the IPRS program to be 9.11 percent ad valorem for R.B.
 Agarwalla, 18.14 percent ad valorem for Carnation, 30.92 percent ad valorem for Crescent,
 65.83 percent ad valorem for Govind, 39.17 percent ad valorem for Kajaria, 8.00 percent
 ad valorem for RSI, 41.08 percent ad valorem for Serampore and 25.33 percent ad valorem
 for all other firms.

 Comment 9: The exporters argue that it is inappropriate to calculate IPRS benefits based on
 when benefits are received because, even though payment is not received for months after
 shipment, the program provides known payments on a sale-by-sale basis. The Department
 should calculate the benefit from the IPRS using payments claimed during the review
 period, rather than payments received during the review period.
 Conversely, the petitioner argues that the Department should be consistent from one
 review to the next and continue to use the total amount of IPRS payments received during
 the review period in calculating the benefit from this program.

 Department's position: We agree with petitioner. It has been our general practice to
 compute benefits received by a firm during the review period (in this case the 1985
 calendar year), and apply them to the total value of exports for the same period. There are a
 few exceptions to this practice, such as when a benefit is earned on a shipment-by-shipment
 basis and the exact amount of the benefit is known at the time of export (see e.g., Final
 Affirmative Countervailing Duty Determination and Countervailing Duty Order;
 Certain Steel Wire Nails from New Zealand (52 FR 37196; October 5, 1987)). Even if we were
 to consider the IPRS such an exception, the exporters did not make such a claim when we
 first determined in the 1984 review of this order that the IPRS provided a countervailable
 subsidy. In that review, we calculated the subsidy from the IPRS program by allocating
 receipts over exports. The use of the lag in payments from this new program resulted in
 lower benefits than would have been the case if we had measured the subsidy based on IPRS
 claims during the 1984 review period. Furthermore, a shift in methodology at this time
 would result in a substantial gap in the measurement of subsidies from this program (i.e.,
 IPRS payments claimed in 1984 but received in 1985 would be excluded from not only 1984
 but 1985 as well).

 Comment 10: The petitioner argues that the Department incorrectly determined that the
 benefit from the IPRS program is zero for purposes of the cash deposit of estimated
 countervailing duties. While it is the Department's policy to adjust the deposit rate if a
 program-wide change has taken place since the review period but prior to publication of the
 preliminary results of administrative review, the exporters' renunciation of IPRS payments
 on exports of the subject merchandise to the United States does not constitute a program-
 wide change because it was not effectuated by an official act, statute, regulation or decree,
 and the exporters could resume receiving IPRS payments if they chose.
 The exporters respond that the Department verified that no exporter was permitted to
 receive IPRS payments on sales to the United States of the subject merchandise and that
 this change applied to all exporters without exception. The Engineering Export Promotion
 Council (EEPC) issued a decree, verified by the Department, terminating IPRS payments for
 exports of subject castings to the United States. The EEPC is an official body legally
 sanctioned by the Indian Ministry of Commerce. A change that affects the entire program
 and affects equally all exporters under that program is a program-wide change.
 Accordingly, the exporters argue that the Department correctly determined that this
 program-wide change meets the Department's requirements for setting a deposit rate
 different from the net subsidy determined for the review period.

 Department's position: We agree with the exporters. At verification, we established that the
 EEPC stopped accepting any IPRS claims filed on shipments of the subject merchandise
 exported to the United States after July 1, 1987. The Ministry of Commerce has
 subsequently enforced the renunciation. Allowing for the normal lag of a few months
 between the filing of IPRS 

*50751

 claims and the receipt of payment, there is no evidence
 or reason to believe that IPRS payments will be received by any exporters after publication
 of the preliminary results. Therefore, for purposes of the cash deposit of estimated
 countervailing duties, we determine the benefit from this program to be zero.

 Comment 11: The exporters claim that Crescent inadvertently failed to include in the
 questionnaire response a revision to the amount of income tax benefit it received under
 section 80HHC and, with the submission of the revised information, argue that the
 Department should recalculate its benefit accordingly.

 Department's position: We disagree. Section 355.31(b) of the Department's regulations does
 not allow for submission of factual information after the date of publication of the
 preliminary results. Crescent's submission was untimely.

 Comment 12: The exporters argue that the Department overstated Carnation's benefit from
 the Income Tax Deduction under section 80HHC by incorrectly applying a 68.25 percent
 tax rate, instead of the 63 percent rate applicable to Carnation. Although the exporters
 acknowledge that the verification report and the questionnaire response show that
 Carnation's tax rate is 68.25 percent, they claim this information is incorrect.

 Department's position: We disagree. The exporters' assertion that this information is
 incorrect was untimely and unsubstantiated.

 Comment 13: The exporters argue that the Department overstated Uma's, Agarwalla's and
 Kejriwal's benefits from the Income Tax Deduction under section 80HHC by incorrectly
 applying a 63 percent tax rate, instead of the rates applicable to partnerships.

 Department's position: We agree and have corrected our calculations by applying an 18
 percent tax rate to Uma and a 21 percent tax rate to Agarwalla and Kejriwal. These are the
 rates that the partnerships actually paid during the review period. Accordingly, we
 determine the net subsidy from this program to be 0.21 percent ad valorem for R.B.
 Agarwalla, 1.18 percent ad valorem for Carnation, 5.48 percent ad valorem for Crescent,
 11.81 percent ad valorem for Govind, 0.83 percent ad valorem for Kajaria, zero for RSI,
 0.12 percent ad valorem for Serampore and 0.62 percent ad valorem for all other firms.

 Comment 14: The exporters argue that a separate and greater deposit rate for Govind is
 inappropriate. Govind received benefits under the section 80HHC income tax provision
 during the 1985 assessment year. Because the income tax provision changed substantially
 between 1985 and 1986, the Department has no basis to set a greater deposit rate based on
 prior findings. Furthermore, the benefit of a tax program will always vary depending upon
 profits, and profits vary from year to year. Therefore, all companies should be considered
 as benefitting equally from a tax reduction program until the actual company- specific
 profit/loss data demonstrate otherwise.

 Department's position: We disagree. We calculate deposit rates based upon the amount of
 benefits each company received during the review period, except where program-wide
 changes have been demonstrated prior to the notice of preliminary results of review.
 Because we have no basis for assuming what the future benefit will be in any given program,
 we have consistently determined the deposit rate based upon prior benefit levels. We have
 determined the deposit rates for all companies based upon their respective net subsidies in
 1985. It would be inappropriate to treat Govind differently from the rest.

 Comment 15: The exporters argue that the Department overstated the benefit to Govind,
 RSI, Uma and Serampore from packing credit loans by incorrectly allocating the benefits
 over castings exports rather than all exports. The companies reported packing credit loans
 used to finance all exports not castings exports alone, and the Department should have
 divided by each company's exports of all products.

 Department's position: We agree and have corrected our calculations accordingly. We
 determine the benefit from packing credit loans to be 0.49 percent ad valorem for R.B.
 Agarwalla, zero for Carnation, zero for Crescent, 1.22 percent ad valorem for Govind, 4.84
 percent ad valorem for Kajaria, 1.06 percent ad valorem for RSI, 0.22 percent ad valorem
 for Serampore and 0.44 percent ad valorem for all other firms.

 Comment 16: The petitioner claims that the Department incorrectly allocated Serampore's
 benefit from post-shipment preferential financing over castings exports to all markets.
 Because Serampore reported post-shipment financing only on sales to the United States, the
 benefit should be allocated over castings exports to the United States.
 
Department's position: We disagree. Serampore exported castings only to the United States.
 Therefore, castings exports to all markets and castings exports to the United States are the
 same.

 Comment 17: The exporters argue that Govind had commercial borrowings during the
 review period at a 15 percent annual rate of interest. Therefore, the Department should
 revise its calculation of the benefits from export packing and pre-shipment financing.

 Department's position: We disagree. Information in the record shows the Govind's
 commercial borrowing rate was 16.5 percent during the review period. Nevertheless, the
 Department does not use company specific-benchmarks, rather we use one benchmark for
 all companies based on the average interest rate commercially available for short-term
 borrowings in the country during the review period (see Final Results of Countervailing
 Duty Administrative Review; Ceramic Tile from Mexico (53 FR 15091; April 27, 1988)).

 Comment 18: The petitioner claims that the Department inadvertently understated Super
 Castings' benefit from post-shipment financing because of a transposition of numbers.

 Department's position: We agree and have corrected our calculation accordingly. We
 determine the benefit from this program to be 0.45 percent ad valorem for Serampore, zero
 for R.B. Agarwalla, Carnation, Crescent, Govind, Kajaria, and RSI, and 0.98 percent ad
 valorem for all other firms.

 Comment 19: The exporters claim that castings exporters paid an insurance premium to the
 Export Credit Guarantee Corp. (ECGC) in order to utilize the preferential packing credit.
 Since castings exporters can borrow commercially without paying such a premium, the
 Department should deduct the cost of the premium paid from the benefit received under
 packing credit financing.

 Department's position: We disagree. The cost of export credit insurance is not an offset to a
 benefit as defined by section 771(6)(A) of the Tariff Act (see the Department's position in
 response to Comment 2). Credit insurance is part of the cost of obtaining pre-shipment
 financing and, as such, is part of the calculation of the effective interest on these loans.
 However, we lack sufficient information to derive an effective interest rate benchmark.
 Therefore, we can only compare a nominal interest rate benchmark to a nominal
 preferential interest rate.

 Comment 20: The exporters claim that the Department used an incorrect Indian rupee/U.S.
 dollar exchange rate to convert Crescent's reported sales values from dollars to rupees.

 Department's position: We disagree. We used an average annual exchange 

*50752

 rate
 based on verified information obtained from the Central Bank of India. The exporters
 presented no evidence that this information is incorrect.

 Comment 21: The petitioner argues that the Department should not accept Kejriwal's
 allocation of its MDA grant when calculating the benefit from the grant. Kejriwal's
 representatives used MDA grant money to attend trade fairs in both Atlanta and Toronto.
 However, because Kejriwal provided neither information detailing the duration of its
 representatives' stay in each city nor a list of contacts made in each city, the Department
 should not accept the allocation offered by Kejriwal. Instead, the Department should
 allocate the total amount of the grant based solely on Kejriwal's sales of castings to the
 United States.
 The exporters respond that the Department verified that the MDA grant was used for
 meetings both within and outside of the United States, and argue that it is appropriate to
 allocate half of the grant over exports to the United States.
 
Department's position: We agree with the exporters. We verified that Kejriwal applied for
 the MDA grant for meetings in Atlanta and Toronto. We also verified that the
 representatives did, in fact, attend meetings in the two cities. Allocating the grant equally
 between the two cities is reasonable.

 Comment 22: The petitioner argues that the responding companies failed to provide specific
 information detailing their transactions in which the central sales tax (CST) and the West
 Bengal sales tax (WBST) apply to purchases of pig iron. In the absence of such information,
 the Department should assume that the CST and WBST do not apply to purchases of pig iron
 when calculating the benefit attributable to the Cash Compensatory Scheme (CCS).

 Department's position: We disagree. The official record demonstrates a reasonable and
 documented calculation of the indirect tax incidence on exported castings. Where we had
 no evidence that pig iron was purchased from dealers in the West Bengal state, we did not
 include the WBST in the amount of taxes paid and rebated on pig iron.

 Comment 23: The petitioner claims the Department inadvertently understated the average
 f.o.b. value per metric ton of pig iron in its calculation of Kejriwal's tax rebate through the
 CCS program.

 Department's position: We agree and have corrected our calculation accordingly. We still
 find no overrebate of indirect taxes to Kejriwal from the CCS program.

 Comment 24: The petitioner argues that the Department failed to measure the indirect tax
 incidence and compare it to the rebate provided under the CCS program for Super Castings
 and Kajaria.

 Department's position: We agree and have measured the indirect tax incidence and rebate
 from the CCS program for Super Castings and Kajaria. We determine the benefit from the CCS
 program to be zero for both companies.

 Final Results of Review

 After reviewing all of the comments received, we determine that the following net subsidies
 exist for the period January 1, 1985 through December 31, 1985:
   
  --------------------------------------------- 
  Manufacturer/exporter   Net subsidy (percent) 
  --------------------------------------------- 
 R.B. Agarwalla .......................... 9.81 
 Carnation .............................. 19.32 
 Crescent ............................... 36.40 
 Govind ................................. 78.86 
 Kajaria ................................ 44.84 
 RSI ..................................... 9.06 
 Serampore .............................. 41.87 
 All other firms ........................ 27.37 
  --------------------------------------------- 
   
 The Department will instruct the Customs Service to assess countervailing duties at the
 above percentages of the f.o.b. invoice price on shipments of the subject merchandise
 exported on or after January 1, 1985, and on or before December 31, 1985.
 As a result of the termination of benefits attributable to the IPRS program, the Department
 will also instruct the Customs Service to collect a cash deposit of estimated
 countervailing duties of 13.03 percent of the f.o.b. invoice price for Govind and 2.21
 percent for all other firms on shipments of this merchandise entered, or withdrawn from
 warehouse, for consumption on or after the date of publication of these final results of
 administrative review.
 This administrative review and notice are in accordance with section 751(a)(1) of the Tariff
 Act (19 U.S.C. 1675(a)(1)) and 19 CFR 355.22.
 Dated: November 30, 1990.

 Marjorie A. Chorlins,

 Acting Assistant Secretary for Import Administration.

 [FR Doc. 90-28894 Filed 12-7-90; 8:45 am]

 BILLING CODE 3510-DS-M